Understanding decision-making: Inherent risk preferences
When making intuitive decisions, individuals are rarely risk-neutral or consistently risk-averse

How do individuals make decisions in situations involving risk? How do we instinctually trade off the potential for a gain with the potential for loss?
Most individuals fear losses more than they like gain — we are loss averse — and the choice of reference point shifts our perception of gains and losses.
And individuals find small chances of large payoffs quite attractive, as if magnifying the probabilities of larger outcomes.
When making intuitive decisions, individuals are rarely risk-neutral or consistently risk-averse. Instead, their attitudes may vary from extremely risk-averse to quite risk-seeking, depending on the risk profile.
Specifically, individuals hate losing, which makes them generally risk-averse when trading off gains and losses, but they become risk-seeking when it comes to doubling down to avoid a sure loss or when they have a small chance of a large gain.
When trading off a potential loss with a potential gain, individuals behave as if losses count more than gains.
There are multiple values that a reference point can take. Determining which reference point individuals use is both an art and a science, and an active area of research.
The existing evidence suggests three factors that determine the reference point.
Loss aversion and decision weights make us act in a risk-avoiding way in some circumstances and in a risk-seeking way in others. Risk aversion keeps us away from financial disaster. Too much risk aversion, however, also implies that we will not get very far in the long run. For example, once we discover a good business opportunity or a profitable investment strategy, we may avoid doubling down, because increasing the stakes produces apprehension. Keeping their foot on the gas pedal for good opportunities is what differentiates great investors such as Warren Buffet from others.
How about seeking risks? Betting on long shots and buying lottery tickets is fun and exciting, but it is profitable for only a minority of lucky winners. As probability becomes small, the premiums we pay may become very large. And small odds mean the premiums will not be large in absolute terms (e.g., the small cost of a lottery ticket or an overpriced insurance product).
The most worrisome pattern is being risk-seeking for losses of high probability. This induces a tendency to double down when one is “in the hole" and can easily snowball into larger losses. The following are some examples of the escalation of commitment created by the tendency to take risks to escape a sure loss:
Or, to say it another way: If you go hiking, set a turnaround time.
Individuals are rarely risk-neutral or consistently risk-averse. Instead, their risk attitudes can vary quite a bit depending on what they perceive to be a gain or a loss relative to a reference point, and on whether the situation involves small or large probabilities.
Prospect theory is a framework that organizes these observations, and it consists of three effects:
First Published: Feb 06, 2024, 11:03
Subscribe Now