Forbes India 15th Anniversary Special

Emission taxes on companies may undermine investment but not for environmental reasons

European companies forced to adopt the pro-environmental tax scaled back investment by nearly 1% of total assets

IESE Business School
Published: May 20, 2024 10:32:25 AM IST
Updated: May 20, 2024 05:03:23 AM IST

In deciding to impose taxes on emissions it’s important to consider their consequences for companies, the economy and the environment, as well as to determine whether polluters do actually pay or become greener as a result.
Image: ShutterstockIn deciding to impose taxes on emissions it’s important to consider their consequences for companies, the economy and the environment, as well as to determine whether polluters do actually pay or become greener as a result. Image: Shutterstock

Since Finland introduced the world’s first tax on carbon emissions in 1990, the levy has formed part of policymakers’ toolkits for mitigating climate change: make the polluters pay, and they will change their behavior to contaminate less. In the process, governments will bring in extra tax revenue, ideally earmarked for environment-related projects.

As the search for climate solutions grows more urgent, the World Bank at the end of 2023 registered 37 carbon tax initiatives worldwide, 27 with national scope and 10 at smaller regional levels. A decade earlier, only a dozen countries, mostly in northern Europe, had them. Even today, neither the U.S. nor China has adopted a carbon tax; in total, only 5.6% of estimated greenhouse gas emissions worldwide are covered by them.

But in deciding to impose taxes on emissions it’s important to consider their consequences for companies, the economy and the environment, as well as to determine whether polluters do actually pay or become greener as a result.

Research by IESE’s Martin Jacob, together with Kira Zerwer of WHU-Otto Beisheim School of Management, indicates emission taxes may unexpectedly undermine capital investment while producing limited environmental benefits. The research finds that companies invested less after the introduction of a tax — not because they wanted to curtail pollution but because of the financial burden of the heavier taxation. Particularly impacted were companies unable to pass the extra tax costs on to consumers or suppliers.

“Emission taxes might not have the desired impact,” the study finds, “suggesting that policy makers may utilize other tools from their regulatory toolbox to tackle polluting firms and make them more efficient actors in climate policy.”

Higher taxes, lower investment

The research looks at two neighboring provinces in Spain: Alicante and Murcia. The regional government of Alicante, following European Union directives, quickly introduced an emission tax on sulfur oxides (SOx) and nitrogen oxides (NOx) at the start of 2013; neighboring Murcia did not.

The Alicante reform substantially increased corporations’ tax bills — on average, by 7% compared with their Murcia neighbors — and generated additional compliance costs and a surge in demand for advisory services.

So far, that’s according to plan: make polluters pay more. And almost every new environmental regulation is accompanied by an immediate jump in compliance costs and in demand for consultants, as companies scramble to adjust to different rules. A higher tax bill could be a mark of policy success, even if companies don’t like it.

The problem lies in how firms paid the additional taxes. Often, they did so by cutting back on investments in fixed assets. Companies in Alicante scaled back investment by nearly 1% of total assets, relative to those in Murcia, after the introduction of the tax.

To test this conclusion in a different setting, the research examined a sample of private European firms in the wake of new carbon dioxide taxes in France and Ireland — and also found that companies in those countries reduced investment by about 1% of total assets.

The decline in investment was greater in markets that were more competitive, where there was less room for maneuver on prices. The decline in investment was also greater in firms in markets with more elastic demand, since companies were unable to pass the increase on to stakeholders such as consumers or suppliers. And it was also greater in firms with less financial flexibility.

Also read: Why decarbonisation is so hard


High and low polluters respond the same

Additionally, there was no link between industry-level emissions of SOx and NOx and investment response: the investment decline was similar across high- and low-polluting industries alike. That means companies were forced to reduce investment for purely economic reasons, independent of environmental considerations.

In fact, high-emitting industries in which tax costs could be passed on to suppliers or customers could continue investing. This happened at the cost of some low-emitting industries that cut investment because they ultimately needed to shoulder part of the emission tax burden through higher input prices from high-emitting industries.

Turning again to France and Ireland, the research finds that the investment response in those countries was unrelated to the level of CO2 emissions in an industry.

Instead, as in Spain, investments of firms operating in more competitive markets, with low pricing power or with low financial flexibility, were the most affected by the CO2 taxes.

And what about actual emissions? In some senses, “pollution level” is the metric that matters most. While this goes beyond the scope of this particular project, additional research using satellite images indicates that NOx levels declined only very modestly in Valencia despite the tax.

These findings underline that, unfortunately, there’s no single, easy way to convince companies to go green. A simple tax on emissions may not be the answer.

Policymakers must develop a more complex toolkit, including measures such as tax incentives for dirty firms to invest in green technology, and a binding and effective cap on the volume of emissions. hidden messages behind “jump bidding” in auctions.
 
Martin Jacob, Professor in the Accounting & Control Department at IESE. He is an expert on emission taxes and their effects on investment, sustainability and the environment.

[This article has been reproduced with permission from IESE Business School. www.iese.edu/ Views expressed are personal.]